IPcentral Weblog
  The DACA Blog

Friday, January 27, 2006

 
Post-Trinko: Toward an Holistic Approach to Antitrust and Broadband Regulation
(previous | next)
 

Given the eminence of the other speakers on yesterday's ABA panel regarding antitrust in the broadband world, it is not surprising that the discussion went far beyond debating various interpretations of the Supreme Court's Trinko decision. We also explored -- the Court's opinion aside -- the extent to which antitrust should serve as a backstop to FCC regulation.

But taking FCC regulation largely as given and then considering the proper role for antitrust may not go far enough; our talk raised issues that made me wish we had considered the interplay between antitrust and regulation more holistically. Given the general agreement that competitive analysis will be a critical element of the government's involvement with broadband going forward, policymakers should begin to develop consensus regarding which arm of government should conduct that analysis and why.

That competitive analysis must figure prominently in the legal and regulatory treatment of broadband derives largely from the demise (in coherence, at least) of the Communications Act's scheme for regulating communications services differently depending on how each is classified. This scheme originated when services were provided over specialized networks, each of which was presumed to have unique economic and other characteristics. Broadband and the Internet disrupt this scheme by enabling the introduction of services that do not fit the Act's classifications, and by making services increasingly agnostic as to the underlying network infrastructure. But policymakers cannot solve this problem simply by creating new classifications, for those would become outdated, too. The logical alternative is to discard the approach of regulating based on service classifications in favor of regulatory intervention predicated on market failures or abuses, i.e., predicated on competitive analysis.

Assuming government should tailor its involvement with broadband based on competitive analysis, the question becomes: who should perform that the analysis -- the FCC, the antitrust authorities or both?

As some have proposed in the context of reforming the Act, there are reasons to believe that responsibility for competitive analysis should rest, in the first instance, with the FCC and other agency regulators. This view presumes that communications retains elements (often ill-defined) favoring the development of unique expertise to analyze markets in the industry. Thus, agency experts are deemed preferable to generalist courts and prosecutors. Some also favor administrative law because of its tendency, at least historically, to regulate markets prospectively, which provides more certainty for parties expecting to benefit from such regulation.

Alternatively, there are reasons to think antitrust authorities may be best suited to analyze communications markets. Antitrust authorities' responsibility to police multiple industries may afford them more sophisticated economic knowledge, along with the modesty that comes with knowing first-hand that many actions taken by firms reflect vigorous (and legitimate) efforts to capitalize on competitive advantage, rather than efforts to undermine competition itself. The process of antitrust, which emphasizes adversarial "discovery" mechanisms and back-end enforcement, also may be better at affording government the detailed information it needs to conduct thorough analyses, while discouraging intervention before mercurial communications markets have settled into a pattern that clearly endangers consumer welfare.

Rather than assuming that competitive analysis must reside with either the FCC or antitrust authorities, however, more attention should be given to looking at both arms of government simultaneously. Certainly this approach would help identify (and thus eliminate) redundancies that are counterproductive; in a few cases, for example, antitrust might not serve as a useful "backstop" giving the FCC comfort to avoid prospective regulation that skews or squelches investment in broadband and other new technologies.

Moreover, an holistic approach would encourage Congress and other policymakers to pick and choose among the features of antitrust and agency regulation, downplaying features that undermine consumer welfare and emphasizing or replicating features that work well (e.g., importing the rigors of adversarial process to the FCC's competitive analysis).

Until policymakers begin to look more broadly at where to locate the government's competitive analysis, debate over Trinko and the role of antitrust generally is likely to mask disagreement regarding the relative institutional competencies of agencies and courts. Policymakers can exploit these competencies more effectively for consumers by identifying the best features of agencies and antitrust authorities and, only then, deciding where in government those features should be deployed to analyze broadband and other evolving communications markets.

posted by Kyle Dixon @ 8:21 AM | Antitrust & Competition Policy , Broadband , Communications , Internet , Supreme Court , The FCC , The FTC

Share |

Link to this Entry | Printer-Friendly

Post a Comment:





 
Blog Main
RSS Feed  
Recent Posts
  EFF-PFF Amicus Brief in Schwarzenegger v. EMA Supreme Court Videogame Violence Case
New OECD Study Finds That Improved IPR Protections Benefit Developing Countries
Hubris, Cowardice, File-sharing, and TechDirt
iPhones, DRM, and Doom-Mongers
"Rogue Archivist" Carl Malamud On How to Fix Gov2.0
Coping with Information Overload: Thoughts on Hamlet's BlackBerry by William Powers
How Many Times Has Michael "Dr. Doom" Copps Forecast an Internet Apocalypse?
Google / Verizon Proposal May Be Important Compromise, But Regulatory Trajectory Concerns Many
Two Schools of Internet Pessimism
GAO: Wireless Prices Plummeting; Public Knowledge: We Must Regulate!
Archives by Month
  September 2010
August 2010
July 2010
June 2010
  - (see all)
Archives by Topic
  - A La Carte
- Add category
- Advertising & Marketing
- Antitrust & Competition Policy
- Appleplectics
- Books & Book Reviews
- Broadband
- Cable
- Campaign Finance Law
- Capitalism
- Capitol Hill
- China
- Commons
- Communications
- Copyright
- Cutting the Video Cord
- Cyber-Security
- DACA
- Digital Americas
- Digital Europe
- Digital Europe 2006
- Digital TV
- E-commerce
- e-Government & Transparency
- Economics
- Education
- Electricity
- Energy
- Events
- Exaflood
- Free Speech
- Gambling
- General
- Generic Rant
- Global Innovation
- Googlephobia
- Googlephobia
- Human Capital
- Innovation
- Intermediary Deputization & Section 230
- Internet
- Internet Governance
- Internet TV
- Interoperability
- IP
- Local Franchising
- Mass Media
- Media Regulation
- Monetary Policy
- Municipal Ownership
- Net Neutrality
- Neutrality
- Non-PFF Podcasts
- Ongoing Series
- Online Safety & Parental Controls
- Open Source
- PFF
- PFF Podcasts
- Philosophy / Cyber-Libertarianism
- Privacy
- Privacy Solutions
- Regulation
- Search
- Security
- Software
- Space
- Spectrum
- Sports
- State Policy
- Supreme Court
- Taxes
- The FCC
- The FTC
- The News Frontier
- Think Tanks
- Trade
- Trademark
- Universal Service
- Video Games & Virtual Worlds
- VoIP
- What We're Reading
- Wireless
- Wireline
Archives by Author
PFF Blogosphere Archives
We welcome comments by email - look for a link to the author's email address in the byline of each post. Please let us know if we may publish your remarks.
 










The Progress & Freedom Foundation